The Hidden History of Eurodollars, Part 1: Cold War Origins - podcast episode cover

The Hidden History of Eurodollars, Part 1: Cold War Origins

Jan 14, 202534 min
--:--
--:--
Listen in podcast apps:

Episode description

At more than $10 trillion outstanding, the eurodollar market is one of the biggest forms of shadow banking activity out there. It's also one of the most interesting markets in existence, allowing non-US banks to hold and lend offshore dollars that effectively sit outside of the Federal Reserve's control. But where did eurodollars actually come from? Why did the US allow these "shadow dollars" to exist at all? And what do eurodollars mean for the greenback's role in the global financial system? In this special three-part series, we look back at the hidden history of the eurodollar market. The story is told by Columbia Law School Professor Lev Menand and Federal Reserve Bank of New York Policy Advisor Josh Younger. We start in the aftermath of World War II, when Europe is in the midst of an expensive reconstruction and the world is in the early throes of the Cold War. It's here that the eurodollar is born.

Read more:
Russia Sanctions Arm Trump for Talks With Putin
Scholz Steps Up Criticism of Trump’s Expansionist Rhetoric

Only Bloomberg.com subscribers can get the Odd Lots newsletter in their inbox — now delivered every weekday — plus unlimited access to the site and app. Subscribe at bloomberg.com/subscriptions/oddlots

See omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.

Transcript

Speaker 1

Bloomberg Audio Studios, podcasts, radio news.

Speaker 2

Joe, Joe, what's the noise?

Speaker 3

Where's this going?

Speaker 2

Tracy, I'm setting the scene?

Speaker 3

What was that?

Speaker 1

All right, let's just start.

Speaker 2

I'm Joe Wisenthal and I'm Tracy Alloway and this is a very special edition of the All Thoughts podcast.

Speaker 4

Tracy.

Speaker 1

So, one thing I've been really fascinated by, and I mentioned it on some episodes lately, I've been really getting into Cold War history actually, and I guess I don't know, probably because I'm a middle aged man and that's a middle aged man hobby. You start reading about twentieth century history,

but particularly Soviet and Chinese history. And one thing I've learned, and this did actually come up on an old episode, there's some interesting financial linkages in the past that people might not have expected at all, and I feel like more people should be talking about this.

Speaker 2

I agree. And also, if you like Cold War history, Joe, you are going to love what we are about to do, because there is a big connection between the history of the Cold War and the development of the modern financial system, and that connection is euro dollars. And of course, just to be clear, this is not the euro dollar exchange rate.

Speaker 1

I will fully admit that it took me ten years, like ten years, maybe less, maybe five, No, it probably was closer to ten. That euro dollar did not mean the euro the EU R USD exchange rate.

Speaker 2

It can be admittedly confusing, So why don't we just define it right away? So euro dollars are dollar denominated bank deposits held at foreign banks or overseas branches of US banks. And you can think of them as basically offshore dollars that sit outside the US banking system and kind of away from the Federal Reserve. They're basically a very special form of money. You could call them shadow money.

Speaker 1

And it's totally gigantic. So it's almost ten trillion dollar And I just find it so interesting, right because when I think of dollars, they're either coming from you know, the government spends dollars into existence or US bank credit. US banks licensed to de facto create dollars or deposits it will.

Speaker 4

And yet euro.

Speaker 1

Dollars are kind of this weird thing, I guess, because they're not that.

Speaker 2

Yeah, they're not either of those. And euro dollars didn't just spring up fully formed out of thin air. They were the result of a series of decisions, all aimed at solving particular problems. And that's what we're going to hear about today. So the origins of the euro dollar market, and this story has a lot in it. There's political intrigue, rivalry between the East and West, big existential questions about the role of the US dollar itself in the global

financial system. Just a lot of fascinating history to satisfy your new middle aged man fans.

Speaker 1

Thank you. And we literally literally have the perfect guests to tell this story.

Speaker 2

While we're trapped in this bunker or vault.

Speaker 1

Yeah, you might recognize our storytellers. We're going to be speaking once again with Levmnand and Josh Younger.

Speaker 4

I'm levmanand I'm a law professor at Columbia Law School, where I study money and banking and the history of central banking.

Speaker 5

I'm Josh Younger. I'm a policy advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and the views I am going to express are my own and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.

Speaker 1

They have been digging deep into archives and are ready to tell us the story of the hidden History of Your Dollars in this very special series. There's going to be three episodes with Levin.

Speaker 2

Josh and because it's so good, they tell the story so well, Joe and I aren't going to say anything at all. We're just going to listen in.

Speaker 1

I love this. We should do all of our episodes like that, where we just get to.

Speaker 2

There, just cut ourselves out, all right, let's do it.

Speaker 5

So euro dollars are among the most important financial instruments in the world, really the backbone of the global dollar system. But they come from a very humble beginnings, very idiosyncratic start, and really it all started in Yugoslavia. And I mean that quite literally. This is like the original sin that leads to the development of euro dollars, and it starts

especially when Marshal Tita takes over in Yugoslavia. So in nineteen forty five and November there's a communist revolution and the US is miffed in a bunch of ways, but one of them is that the old government owes them money, and so the question is how are they going to get it? And a few months later, Tito asked for his gold back because the Yugoslav government had seventy million dollars worth of gold in New York, and the Secretary of State, George Marshall, of the Marshall Plan, he realizes

he's got a bargaining ship, which is the gold. It's in New York, and they don't get it back until they settle their claims. Now, even people within the State Department were kind of skeptical of this. The Yugoslavian government is obviously furious, and so the Russians, who at this point, you know, Tito and Stallin have a falling out eventually a few years later, but at this point they're quite closely aligned, and so the Russians are furious. The Yugoslavian

government is furious. The State Department internally has some turmoil over this, and they take it to the UN, which has just been constituted, and the UN says pass they won't consider the claim, and so the Russians get the sense that the US is willing to use gold as a bargaining ship. They'd previously actually been building up dollar balances in New York. This is kind of a misnomer

about the post war period. There's this sense that the Russians are extracting all their resources from but they're actually building up reserves of dollars because the thought is, we're probably going to need to trade with these people. We have a trading company based in the US, and they need resources, and so they're building up foreign currency deposits and gold. But in nineteen forty seven they realize it's not going to go well potentially, and they.

Speaker 3

Pull all the gold out.

Speaker 5

They actually just called banks in New York and they say, we want to go back, a massive reversal of the policy. And the questions where's it going to go? And so they need dollars because the US dollar is the currency of foreign exchange. If they want to trade with the West, they have to trade in dollars. They need gold because

gold is the basis for the monetary system. And so the question is where can they put gold and dollars in a safe place that's still on the right side of what was then already known as the Iron Curtain. And so it turns out Paris is the ticket. They've actually been secretly stockpiloting cash and gold in Paris. They put it in briefcases. They would fly people to Paris and put it in the consulate offices. They would just

build up piles of cash and gold. And in particular there's a bank b SENT that I won't try to do it in French and BCN is owned by or run by a notorious communist synthesizer who has a very

good relationship with the Palaparo. And so there's a friendly bank and so they take on deposit the Soviet money and Bsen's moniker and the telex system that they used to communicate was Eurobank, and so euro dollars were initially in the late forties just deposits issued by Eurobank BCN generally for the Soviet, so they're also for the Chinese.

And slowly this starts to percolate. There's another communist O one bank in London, there's one in Brussels which DCIA just describes as run by someone with few scruples, I think was the way they put it. And so there's some friendlies across Europe are willing to take their money, and the euro dollar market begins this way, which is preempt to sanctions evasion, basically that we might be sanctioned.

It happened to Tito, it might happen to us, and so we need a safe place to go, and the European regulations allowed for this, and they need dollars again because they trade with the West, and so the first severe dollars is for that, and also to replace the salaries of striking French coal miners. See an Their potential place to do this is the record's not super clear.

Speaker 4

I think it's worth pausing here for a second to ask why wouldn't the Soviets have just been in France all along? Why were they in New York initially? Why had another people thought of this? And I think the answer is the dollar liabilities of communist sympathizing French bank are not the same thing as the dollar liabilities of

a bank headquartered in New York. And I think it's helpful to think about why we even hold the dollar liabilities of a bank headquartered in New York, Like even today, when you log onto your bank account and you see a balance five thousand dollars, ten thousand dollars, the bank doesn't hold US government dollars to back that, and yet we are very comfortable treating those as equivalent. We aren't concerned that those those dollars are not the same thing.

And why is that? There's a number of factors that go into it. Of course, since nineteen thirties, we've had deposit insurance up to a two hundred and fifty thousand dollars balance. Of course, businesses routinely hold larger balances and they are comfortable treating them as equivalent. Well, there's the implicit backing of the United States that comes from the fact that your bank was actually chartered by the US government, it's supervised by the US government. There's a sense that

it's backed by the US government. And then there's the actual institutional apparatus of the Federal Reserve, which has a facility the discount window. And if you do go to your bank and say I actually want to turn this balance into government cash, the bank can go to the Federal Reserve and get that cash. The FED can print it for the bank and hand it over. And so there's this whole apparatus that facilitates you treating your balance

at a US bank as equivalent to government cash. Those are trading at par This bank over in France that's now issuing these dollar liabilities that the Soviets are holding.

Why should we think that that should maintain par equivalents to US government dollars, that bank's not FDIC insured, that bank's not chartered by the US government, that bank's not supervised by the US government, and that bank can't call up the FED when the Soviets are drawing down their balance, and the FED won't print money and hand it over.

And so this move by the Soviets, they're taking on a lot of risk to get out of the US, and they're doing it because they're worried about the risk on the other side, the Yugoslavia risk, the risk that the US will actually freeze their balances, and so they have much higher risk tolerance, and they are willing to go out and try something different, which is whole dollar balances offshore.

Speaker 5

And it's the risk for the bank taking it as well, because the question for Beesson and others is what are you going to do with this money. So there's actually an antecedent to the eurodona market from the twenties when the dollar is actually the global reserve currency in the twenties,

and then it lost that status in the thirties. But at that time dollar acceptances, which is a form of trade finance, were larger than ones drawn on London, and the dollar was the currents eve international trade and in particular the reserve currency of the world. It was the largest, was much bigger than Stirling, at least for a few years. And as a consequence of that, some of the Austrian

banks in particularly started issuing dollar deposits. There's one in particular in Austria that did a pretty brisk business in this, and they were doing inter bank deposits. They were doing private deposits like non bank deposits. It looked a lot like the euro dollar market. The difference is they were basically holding it in cash on the other side, so it was more of a correspondent custody type arrangement. And so the question for a bank taking deposits is not

are you comfortable issuing deposits? Of course they're comfortable issuing deposits. What are you going to do with the money? And so what can a communist own bank in Paris in nineteen forty eight do with the money? And at the time there was still some trade between the East and

the West cross Iron Curtain. Now the Soviets don't like this in general because they have this policy of self reliance for obviously, since they don't want to rely in the West for anything, and we actually don't know how much of their trade this was because you'd be sent to the goolog for talking about economic data, So no talking about payrolls Joe in Soviet Russia in the forties, at least starting in the forties. But the key was there was enough to make a business out of it,

and it was in dollars. So using these dollar deposits to finance East West cross Iron Curtain trade was profitable in two respects. One is you just making more money on loans and you make on cash. The others you don't have to hedge it because you have a dollar asset a dollar loan to facilitate trade, and a dollar liability a dollar deposit, so you're not taking foreign exchange risk. And so that turns out to be an okay business. Like there's not enough of that to make for a

large market, but it grows. You know, it's two hundred million dollars in the early fifties and so like this is the seed that's planted, and it basically sets a precedent, which is banks are willing to do this. But the question is how do you make this a bigger business? What are the business opportunities to do it, and that's where the early fifties are a critical period because after the war, most foreign exchange markets are you're straight up closed.

The British in particular are like heavily controlling their currency. London's the obvious place to do this kind of business.

Speaker 3

It's still a.

Speaker 5

Center for international trade, but they can't hedge, so if they issue dollar deposits, they're just holding dollars. And unless they have a dollar loan to make, on the other hand, which they didn't necessarily have at the time, you're just warehousing the risk that the dollar depreciates or appreciates relative to sterling, which is ultimately what you pay employees in that's your sterling funder, meaning like you are a British business,

you care mostly about Stirling. Then in nineteen fifty two, as things are starting to improve, the Marshall Plan is mostly done, the dollar gap has been mostly filled. We'll talk about that a little little bit, and things are normalizing, so the British feel comfortable partially liberalizing their foreign exchange markets now, not all at once. The spot meaning today you want to exchange sterling for dollars, the rate at which you can do. That is still heavily controlled by

the Bank of England. It's in a range that's widened, but it's still pretty narrow. But in particular they've liberalized the foreign exchange futures market or forward market. So what is a foreign exchange forward. A foreign exchange forward is I'm going to give you dollars for sterling, not today, maybe tomorrow, maybe in a month, maybe in a year. This is a very very large market today. It's a critical piece of hedging equipment for a bank because you

can use those forwards. If you've borrowed dollars and lent them out for say a year, you don't want to hedge your dollar risk today. You want to hedge it for the return of those dollars in a year. You want a coverage for the full term of the loan. So the forwards market is critical to this, and so the Bank of England says, now you can trade forwards on dollar, sterling and other major currencies, but in particular dollars sterling, and we won't control that rate. So now

there's a hedging instrument. And now banks in London can look around and say what can I do with this? Because there's clearly interest as a precedent for dollar deposits, and then the question is what can I do with it?

Speaker 3

And so they.

Speaker 5

Figure out so it still happens today, which is there's a shortage of dollars in the UK. That means if they were to borrow dollars and functionally lend them out through the FX markets, they can construct arbitrage type arrangements. And by arbitra, I mean I borrow a dollar, I hedge that dollar, I use the sterling proceeds of the hedge to buy an on shore sterling asset, and I collapse the whole thing when everything matures. So this is

just cross border interest rate arbitrage. Today we'd call it a cross currency basis, but it is not perfectly efficient, meaning if there's more demand for dollars or more demand for sterling, the pricing can get out of whack relative to the relative.

Speaker 3

Interest rates on those two instruments.

Speaker 5

And so the banks in London and particular Midland Bank realizes that if they issue Euro dollars, use the dollars they borrow through year dollar issuance to buy sterling assets and hedge that package, they can make arbitrage profits and so the first use case of your dollars is sanctions evasion. The second use is to facilitate cross iron curtain trade, although that's a pretty small business. And so the third and much larger business is cross border interest rate arbitrage.

And that sounds really technical, but what it's really doing is using foreign exchange markets and derivative markets to source dollars that the UK particular needs in this post war environment. So imagine a euro dollar bank. A eurobank takes in a euro a dollar deposit, which means it gets a dollar in cash. Let's think of a physical bill. That's an asset. It issues a euro dollar liability, and then what is it going to do next, because it needs

to do some sort of investing. And what it does is it exchanges that dollar asset for a sterling cache and it invests that sterling cash in some short term sterling investment that's short bills or something like that. And after it does that, it says, I want to hedge my foreign exchange risk because now I have a dollar liability and a sterling asset, So I'm going to use the foreign exchange forward market to agree to sell that sterling back for dollars at some point in the future

at a fixed price that we agree on today. So that's the bank's position. Who's on the other side of that trade. Let's say a corporation, a manufacturing entity. They

make radios, and that radio production process requires inputs. Those inputs are imported, and so that radio production company needs dollars with which to buy the raw materials that it uses to make the radio that it then sells four dollars in foreign markets, and so they get those dollars from the Eurobank in exchange with the sterling they have

on hand. They go buy all the parts, but they want to make sure that they know how much they're going to receive in local currency at the end of the production process when they sell that radio broad They don't want the value of the dollar to go down, so they sell those dollars forward in exchange for sterling, and so they ventured into a derivative agreement, which is the opposite of the one that the Eurobank has or

the eurobanking system. And so then they put together the radio, they sell it abroad, they receive dollar proceeds, turn those into sterling, which is what they pay their employees in that's what they pay for their land and equipment in and that exchange rate was the one they agreed upon

in advance through the foreign Exchange forward contract. And so basically what's happening is the eurobanks are pulling in dollars from abroad, distributing them through the foreign exchange market that's trading on shore to those that need dollars today, and then providing hedges to those that will receive dollars in the future, and in the case of the Eurobank, the dollars they'll owe in the future potentially to the euro dollar deposit holder.

Speaker 4

Think about this from the perspective of the city of London coming out of the war and those bankers and the world that they grew up in, which is a world that we've completely forgotten, but was the world of sterling dominance before the First World War and the role that the Empire played in financing global trade. What we're looking at in the fifties is a group of London based financial institutions trying to figure out a way to continue their dominance in global economy that runs on dollars

now and not on starling. And so the euro dollars are sort of worth the risk to the City of London and to some extent to UK financial regulators like the Bank of England, because they need to fix their business model for a dollar world, and they want to get in on the dollar world. Dealing in dollars is going to be a necessary part of that, and so the UK is adapting here by turning to dollars and embracing dollar liabilities for its own institutions.

Speaker 5

And in the UK this was a particular problem because they imported so much of what they used to produce products that were manufactured to sell finish goods abroad, and so there's a great newsreel from the late forties for the British populations and you have to go without today for high quality, clean manufactured goods so that we can export as much as possible and source the dollars. But another way to do it is to get euro dollars.

Speaker 6

The Smith household is very dissatisfied. Dad wants a new wallace, mother wants a sewing machine, and Betty wants glamorous beauty preparations. But these are needed for export because we must build up overseas markets. We sell these goods overseas for foreign currency to buy the food and raw materials we need to live and work. These things would soon vanish if we couldn't pay for them. We must sell the things we'd like to buy the things.

Speaker 5

We need, and so this cross border interest rate arbitrage is really just a way markets distribute the currency according to who needs it and provide the hedges that facilitate the functioning of British corporations as well. It's what we'd

call now like a use case. Right, there's like a real underlying use case that doesn't involve the Soviet Union for dollar deposits issued by non US banks, which you can't emphasize enough how fundamentally strange that is, because if I tried to make dollars by writing another piece of paper, I don't think I'd get very far. But at the time that's essentially what these banks are doing, and in particular London is a more let's say, reputable locale, particularly

banks that are not known to be Communist sympathizers. There's a little bit of a funny thing about being a communist bank, but we won't get into that specifically, but these are blea chip banks in London issue even dollar deposits and that means you can use them for things and you can feel more comfortable. Along the lines of what Love was talking about, you can feel much more comfortable with Midland Bank, which was among the largest in the city, than BSEN, which is a tiny little place

on the continent. And so the market starts growing. It has a bunch of things going for it, and the most important, arguably is that they can pay higher interest rates than banks in the US in general. I think you've done podcasts before about the impact of regulation Q at different times. Regulation Q is a ceiling interest rates

that banks can pay. It's a depression your regulation designed to mitigate races to the bottom and bad decision making among commercial banks, and so they are limited in what they can pay. Now, we don't have to talk about whether or not that should or should not have been done. It was definitely in place in the fifties and sixties, and so if you go to London there is no regulation queue, so you can offer dollar deposits and pay

a higher rate of return. So that's more money, right, So that's appealing as long as you can get your head around the counterparty risk meeting. This is not a New York Bank they don't have.

Speaker 3

Access to the FED.

Speaker 5

But as long as this market is reasonably small, they have enough dollars on hand, they have enough dollars in reserve.

Speaker 3

You know, maybe I feel comfortable.

Speaker 5

The second is a much more practical thing, which it was just hard to call New York from London. I was somewhat surprised to learn this and reading around, but you know, the first translanted cable for telephone communications is nineteen fifty six, so it's after the first few out

dollars are issued by non communist banks. And even then there were thirty six circuits, which means if you want to call New York from London, you have to wait online for one of thirty six open lines at some point during the day, which could take a long time. Was very expensive and perhaps more problematically, these cables would get cut with some frequency, and so you've got one transatlantic cable that can get cut for any number of reasons,

with indeterminate resolution times, and so it's just hard. There was a telegraph cable, but like that wasn't great, and so basically it's just like annoying to deal with an overseas bank, especially if you need money soon. So New York banks would generally not offer same day liquidity.

Speaker 3

To European customers for obvious reasons.

Speaker 5

And there's a gold rush in the transatlantic cable business. So the next cable comes in fifty eight, there's another one in sixty one, so the capacity expands, but you're still talking about a few dozen lines here. So it's just hard to manage your liquidity.

Speaker 3

Let's say if you have.

Speaker 5

To wait online for six hours to call your bank, and it's a lot easier to walk down the street. And so to the extent that dollars are used for a national trade that trade flows through London, these banks are in London. You know, why not have a local branch essentially of your bank to deal with. And so if you're offering higher interest rates and much greater convenience, it's a very attractive product, and so it grows pretty rapidly.

It's still inhibited on the continent because you haven't restored full convertibility until nineteen fifty eight, but at that point you do, and you have this dramatic expansion, and you're at all deposits, in particular their use for the thing for which they will become famous, which is trade so now most cross border trade or intra European and global trade is done in dollars. That's a breton Woods thing. We'll talk about breton Woods later, but you essentially have

to use dollars to do international trade. You often need to borrow money to facilitate trade. Trade is very heavily dependent on credit. So now you have the beginnings of a real like I said, was a real business when you're doing a cross border arbitrage, but that goes away if enough people do it. Trade is expanding dramatically. The world in the late fifties is growing enormously quickly, and

a lot of that is driven by international trade. So the demand for credit to facilitate that trade is growing just as fast as the trade itself, and a lot of other banks start to get in on the action. So what was a London city bank dominated market city of London banks becomes really international market based in London. So by the early sixties there are a bunch of US banks who have opened branches in London to facilitate

your dollars. They find this to be a good way to get around regulation que because I want to pay up for deposits, I can't do that in New York, I might as well just do it in London. It's all dollars at the end of the day. So they having branches in London. They're Japanese banks in London. There are Continental banks in London. There's euro dollars in Paris and Milan. So it's turning into a real global business, all in dollars, and so that obviously gets everyone's attention

and it starts to raise a few eyebrows. And this is where people start to notice who are not directly involved in the market. It was previously kind of a practitioner's market. If you were involved in international trade, fans you would know about your dollars, but I wouldn't say anyone on the street would know about your dollars now. But if you were involved in finance, now you've heard

of them. That becomes to be more the case, and by the late fifties they attract the attention of the Federal Reserve, who actually gets an inquiry from a third party saying these are interesting, why don't you look into it? And so they dispatch a couple of senior officers, Allen Holmes and Fred Klopstock. Allen Holmes becomes a sower manager eventually, and Fred Klopstock is kind of like this giant of international finance, so though he's at the beginnings of his career.

But senior officers, you know, they run departments and they're sent to Europe on.

Speaker 3

I mean, I would love to go in this work trip.

Speaker 5

It's like twelve different European cities and you know, all good food places, right, and it wasn't easy to get to Europe in nineteen fifty nine. So they go on this like barnstorming tour of Europe, basically talking to anyone who will take the meeting, A bunch of central bankers, a bunch of private bankers, and they come back with this big, thick confidential report that is later summarized for public use. But they have this big report about you know what this thing is, how big it is. They

don't know, by the way, how big it is. They just know it's big. So they know it's at least a billion dollars, which back in the day was a lot of money.

Speaker 4

Although let's size this a little bit, right, it was a billion dollars in say nineteen sixty, which is maybe the equivalent of fifty billion dollars today, that's still half of a tether. You know, tether is you know, one hundred billion dollar basically Euro dollar bank. And so what we have is the FED looking into this market when it has gotten to the point of being about half of the size of tether's balance sheet. So we have way more to go in terms of the growth of

this market subsequent to nineteen sixty. It's still pretty nascent in nineteen sixty. It's where some action is in London. The policymakers here, they're already on top of this at half the size of a tether, and they're off trying to get to the bottom of what's going on.

Speaker 5

And so when they come back, as they say, this is interesting, and this is interesting in two respects. One, is it just weird that you can do this still, You can just write a dollar a piece of paper and people will take it. But they also more importantly say, you know, this makes the dollar more useful. They literally say useful in the report. And so the question is

what does useful mean? And useful in this context means you're earning enough interest on this dollar that you're willing to hold it as a dollar deposit and on the other hand, like you're willing to hold dollars in balances instead of spending them immediately, and so like this is a short term liquid investment in dollars that is appealing, especially to the central banks, which are rapidly accumulating dollars through the growth of international trades, so they need somewhere

to put it. You know, if I'm at central bank, I taken a dollar, I can go turn it in for gold. If I want gold, I can hold it as a dollar, maybe buy treasury security, or I can put it in a year dollar bank, and something like one out of five of the early year dollars maybe more.

Speaker 3

There's some estimates are.

Speaker 5

Up to forty percent or from central banks themselves, European central banks that we're facilitating the market, and so that's a way to keep dollars circulating offshore.

Speaker 3

Not in the US.

Speaker 5

So you have a functional dollar financial system, at least the beginnings of one that doesn't really touch the US financial system. And so that is both interesting but also useful in the sense that this becomes an increasingly valuable tool because behind the scenes of all of this, we're kind of focused on the year dollars themselves, that's not the big story here. The big story is the balance of payments crisis, which is what they called it, which is really just the fact that the US had written

too many claims on its gold. They'd issued a lot of dollars. Those dollars were exchangeable for gold, and now there were way more dollar claims on their pile of monetary gold than there was gold, and increasingly people were turning their dollars in.

Speaker 4

Well before we get to the bread and wood system, just on the usefulness of dollars, I think it's helpful to reflect on how for ordinary people we take for granted the usefulness of the dollar. We don't actually think, should I pay for this coffee with yen? When we're operating the domestic economy, the dollar is just self evidently

the useful form of money. But when you're talking about international trade and finance, currencies are in legitimate competition with each other for uses, and so you know, put your core or treasurer hat on of a nineteen fifty's UK business engaged in import or export. Part of what Josh is illustrating is suddenly the dollar is a more attractive currency to use in various ways because you can maintain dollar balances at a nearby bank that you've banked with,

you have a strong relationship with. You don't need to have some transatlantic relationship with the New York banks. So suddenly there's more transactions that you will do, trade financing and actual trade invoiced and denominated in dollars because suddenly the dollar is a more appealing currency for you. So

the dollar's usefulness has grown. And to the New York Fed team that is looking into this, they are pleased with this development to see that the euro dollar market, this nascent development of European sovereigns essentially is actually going to be a good thing for the currency that we in the United States are creating in terms of its competitiveness with other currencies in the global marketplace.

Speaker 5

So the question at this point is it's innascent market. It's half a tether, and it's unclear whether or not it's become a big, major global actor. We know it eventually becomes that. At the time that's super unclear, but it becomes eventually and soon the solution to a big problem. So your dollars are the solution to a big problem. Because in the background of all of this build up.

There's massive trouble brewing and the whole global edifice of the dollar system is starting to crack, and the question is, you know, how are we going to save it?

Speaker 3

Or should we?

Speaker 1

That was the first installment of our special three part series examining the Origins of Your Dollars. It's so funny to hear about the communist origins of Like, here's this thing that we hear about every day. They're big in the news, et cetera, and it actually had communist origins in the nineteen fifties.

Speaker 2

Yeah. In the next episode, Josh and Lev are going to continue the story into the turbulent nineteen sixties, with that cracking dollar system now morphing into a major campaign issue in the race between John F. Kennedy and Richard Pixon.

Speaker 1

Will it be euro dollars to the rescue? Find out in the next installment.

Speaker 2

But in the meantime, this has been another episode of the Authoughts podcast. I'm Tracy Alloway. You can follow me at Tracy Alloway and.

Speaker 1

I'm Joe Wisenthal. You can follow me at the Stalwart. Follow one of our special guests, levmanand he's at levmanand our other special guest, Josh Younger, He's not on Twitter. Thanks to our producers Kerman Rodriguez at carbin Ermann dash, Ol Bennett at Dashbot and Kilbrooks at Kelbrooks, and special

thanks to our sound engineer Blake Maples. From our odd loads content, go to Bloomberg dot com slash odd Lots, where we have transcripts, a blog, and a daily newsletter and you can chat about all of these topics twenty four to seven in our discord discord dot gg slash odd lots.

Speaker 2

And if you enjoy odd Lots, if you like it when we bring you the hidden history of euro dollars, then please leave us a positive review on your favorite podcast platform. And remember, if you are a Bloomberg subscriber, you can listen to all of our episodes absolutely ad free. All you need to do is find the Bloomberg channel on Apple Podcasts and follow the instructions there. Thanks for listening

Transcript source: Provided by creator in RSS feed: download file