Hey, they're Odd Lots listeners. We have a very special announcement. Joe and I are hosting our annual Front Lots Pub Quiz on Thursday, February thirteenth in New York City, and it's gonna feature some very special guests and prizes. So come test your wits in finance, markets and economics for a chance to win the ultimate Odd Lots glory and hang out with your fellow listeners. Tickets are on sale now at events dot Bloomberg Live dot com, slash Oddlots
Pub Trivia. You can also find links on our Twitter feeds or in the newsletter, and you can find the link also on our show notes. We hope to see you there.
Bloomberg Audio Studios, Podcasts, Radio.
News Joe three hours of euro dollar market history and we can't get enough. I'd love to do more. I love that.
I couldn't even believe that was real. Just I'm being totally Since we're sitting there in the studio listening to Liv and Josh talk about the history of your dollars, a career highlight and ironically.
Definitely a treat I do feel like there's one thing missing, which is like we kind of have to put everything in modern context. Yes, right, We didn't really bring it that up to date. We talked a little bit about the euro dollar's role in like the two thousand and eight crisis. It was a mention of it. But like, let's talk about the current euro dollar market.
Well, can I say something? Yeah, liv don't listen to this whenever we talk financial market plumbing or things of that nature. Yes, Oh, this is like really fascinating, Like this is really interesting topic. And then I was like, how does this matter to anything at all? So I would like to know, So I would like to actually talk a little bit more for real about like how does it actually matter? Because I find it very interesting. But I sometimes forget, like when environment?
Why why did we talk about this for three hours?
I did a deadlist.
I'm both the most popular trade and most successful trader at Citadel that is going viral, uh barges.
This is an after school special, except.
I've decided I'm going to base my entire personality going forward on campaigning for a strategic pork reserve in the US. Black goals, these are the important questions that robots taking over the world.
No, I think that like in a couple of years, the AI will do a really good job of making the Odd Lots podcast. One day that person will have the mandate of Heaven.
How do I get more popular and successful?
We do have the.
Welcome to lots More, where we catch up with friends about what's going.
On right now, because even when Odd Lots is over, there's always lots More.
And we really do have the perfect guest.
Well, Lev Menand is here with us, and he's going to provide an update on the market. He is, of course, an associate professor of law at Columbia School. So Lev, thank you, thank you for coming on and talking to us even more about euro dollars.
I also think this is a topic that we could just keep doing episodes.
No, for sure, do an all thoughts spin off on your dollars.
All the good topics are fractal, and that you could just go down. This is a cool thing I've realized, is that actually the good topics. The only limitation on how many episodes you could do is creativity and depth. But actually we could just do keep going right.
Yeah, And if anything, it matters more today than I did in nineteen sixty four and nineteen fifty four, which was the.
Periods we were called, right, why does it matter more today?
Size and centrality in the US dollar monetary system and in the global financial system. You know, the Euro dollar system right now is probably thirteen thirteen trillion dollars in size, which makes it, you know, more than twice as big as the uninsured deposits in the domestic system, and almost as big as the overall deposits in the domestics system. And it's the leading edge of mind. Minitary expansion in
the US dollar system takes place offshore, not onshore. And when we were talking about the development of this in the fifties and sixties and seventies, the onshore domestically regulated dollar deposit system was a much bigger percentage of the overall hull. And now we're in a world that looks quite a bit different in terms of the relative importance.
And we've been in that world for about twenty five or thirty years now, and the two thousand and eight crisis was a crisis of that world, and twenty twenty was in part a crisis of that world. And so we're now in a financial system where instability in the Euro dollar market that's the main with the addition of the repo market. That's the main area of instability and
concern for our whole system. You know, in the twentieth century, we still had a sort of like you know, your grandparents banking system, and now it's not.
But we have the dollar swap lines, right Like, isn't that the solution to all of the instability, or at least it has been in the past.
The swap lines are both enabling the problem and mitigating the downside consequences. They're enabling the problem because they lead to the ability of euro dollar issuers to draw in Euro dollar holders. When you think about what a euro dollar issuer is doing is they're actually selling a product
that's their liability. It's a money instrument that people can hold who have cash, have demand for cash and cash equivalents in large quantities, and they are competing with domestic US banks that have a really nice product, the deposit that is up to two hundred and fifty thousand dollars per account ensured by the FDIC explicitly, and a whole bunch of other money like products created by other shadow banks. Money market mutual funds create various products, and the swap lines.
The existence of the swap lines is what gives people confidence that, you know, this is a pretty robust money type instrument that has backing from the sort of central bank which is the creator of dollars that makes these money like liabilities money good. And so in order to get such a huge thirteen trillion dollars, such a huge market, you need the swap lines there in the first place to give people confidence to hold large quantities of these
that they will in fact me money good. But the problem you have is that the extent to which the US government stands behind this thirteen trillion dollar dollar money supply, it's ambiguous, it's not explicit. It is like uninsured depodsits
in the domestic system. It's worse, though, but it's similar to it, and so it's highly run a ball and unstable insofar as people aren't the extent to which the system will be supported by the Central Bank of the United States when it gets into trouble in various bad states of the world. So in good times it's fine, but in bad times people decide, you know what, that competing money instrument created in the domestic US banking system, or those t bills are just a much better place
for us to be. We want out, and I have a historical analogy since we've been doing so much history on this. Think about the US system in the nineteen twenties, going to the nineteen thirties, we created the Federal Reserve and the discount window at the Federal Reserve for domestic US banks. It's like a swap line for the banks directly. It's doing what the swap lines are doing. With the addition of the foreign Central Bank. And people thought, oh,
we're going to fix bank runs. We've got this infrastructure setup, we created the central Bank, it's going to accesup all these deposits. And we had the worst bank run ever in the thirty two to thirty three period. What happened. What happened was the FED didn't support all the banks
when push came to shove. The FED allowed a bank called the Bank of the United States, a Jewish run bank based in New York, to fail, and created a lot of uncertainty about the extent of its support for state chartered banks that were not members of the Federal Reserve system, and runs just went throughout the system, and over a third of the banking system ultimately collapsed. Even though we had this support system, and what you saw
in two thousand and eight is a similar problem. People just don't know how much the FED will be there and to what extent, and that can cause systemic catastrophe. And the reason why we got deposit insurance in part in nineteen thirty three as the government saying, you know what, we just have to be explicit about the fact that we're backing these money instruments. We can't have this implicit insurance program that is through FED lending. We got to just be explicit, and that.
Worked really, really well.
This is like that, I mean, this is a principle right that like big blanket guarantees are cheaper right from a dollar basis than sort of back up things that you don't know whether they're gonna come or you try to go cheap right because you're gonna let this bank fail and you're gonna send the messages.
To the other band say you're gonna do whatever it takes and hope that you don't hope that.
You don't have to.
It's like, really, the bazukahs are ultimately would do it. And the beauty of Bazukahs is because they're so intimidating. You don't have to fire them. Ore deposits in the euro dollar market, are the depositors compensated for this ambiguity about run ability?
Of course, so how does that look like?
How is that?
What is that?
So, as a general matter, the way in which shadow money and struments, non deposit deposits, deposit alternatives, money instruments, cash equivalents that are competing with just sort of like your checking account at JP Morgan Chase. They are competing on price. They are paying more interest than obviously your checking account Jamie Morgan Chase, where often you know Jamie Morgan table will just pay you almost zero on that
checking account in terms of interest. And so the euro dollar market all developed, you know, fifties and sixties London banks offering more interest on balances than National City Bank in New York and drawing depositors to their own banks. They could have a deposit account in dollars in London that just paid more interest. And that's the same story you see with the RepA market and money market funds. These are ways to get a little bit more yield
on your cash instruments. They're competing on price, and the main customers historically where the corporate treasurers who had huge cash balances, and there are lots of different customers now who have cash they want a little bit more yield on. The thing that goes wrong in these markets is they are sacrificing MONEINSS, you know, safety, They're sacrificing the extent to which it's really a liability of the United States
government for some more yield. And when we get to a bad state of the world, that trade off starts to look a little bit different, and that's what creates the run dynamic. Suddenly we're in a bad state of the world. Think August two thousand and eight, and you're a reboke counter party of Leman Brothers. You're parking your extra cash and Linen Brothers for a little extra yield, and you think, you know what, I'm just going to
move my balance to a regular bank account. I'm going to go to JP Morgan and just have a big balance there. Yeah, I'm going to be earning a little less yield on my cash, but I know that it's money good and it's going to be available, and you know what, I just don't need to be a rebooke counterparty to Liam Brothers anymore, and that was what brought down Liam Brothers. It was just an old fashioned bank run on its rebo book.
Yeah, collateral crunch. So one thing that stands out in the series is there are these brief windows where regulators basically consider actually regulating euro dollars. But then what happens is like there's a crisis in energy markets or there's a banking crisis, and so everyone decides now is not the time to start fiddling around with Yes.
It's never a good time to regulate.
This is my question, like what would be a good time and what would that regulation actually look like.
It's a really deep and difficult question because you guys may have been following the Basel end game capital Requirements project of the last several years of the US banking regulators and Michael Barr, the Rice chair of the FED for Supervision, who's been leading that project, who has recently announced he's going to step down as vice chair for Supervision, and part of it is just that it seems unlikely that he's going to be able to get that project
over the finish line. And the reason I bring this up is you might think when the banking system is making record profits, and the economy is humming along nicely. Would be a great time to strengthen the regulatory regime. And the Biden administration and its bank regulators have tried to strengthen the domestic you know onshore deposit you know, regulatory regime of domestic deposits, and they've been completely stymied. And so plainly, when things are good, that's not actually
a good time because nobody wants to nobody. Everybody's just work. It's everyone's like, everything is fine. We don't need to make any changes right now, and so the inertia prevents changes, and so actually practically it is during crisis. It happened to be the case that the seventy four crisis that we talked about, they felt like things were too too fragile to do anything. Similarly, in the aftermath of two
thousand and eight there was a similar mindset. You might recall there were more significant reforms discussed and at least mooted privately, including with respect to repo and euro dollar liabilities. And the thought was, we're in a bad recession right now. We should try to get out of that recession, and let's not upset the apple Cart and so clearly a
certain type of crisis is not enough either. If you just look to history, one thing you do see is if the crisis is really bad, not like seventy four or oh heait, but like nineteen thirty three, then you get fundamental structural reform. And so if the euro dollar market were to lead to economic fallout on that, I feel very comfortable predicting that it would be fundamentally reformed.
What would it look like? And I mean part of the question, and I guess Tracy is but I get, like, Okay, the timing one thing, but what would it look like? And also what's to stuff be ever from being a bank and offshore and offering something that I call a dollar.
Yeah, two great questions. So of course it could look like a bunch of different things. There's not one answer. There is the cleanest answer, which is an international agreement like Basil, call it Bazel four. That is quite simple. It says each jurisdiction shall ensure that the financial institutions in that jurisdiction only issue short term money like liabilities
in their own currency. And so if you're a London based bank regulated by UK financial regulators, you cannot issue a dollar demand deposit type liability unless it's fully reserved on the asset side of the bank with a dollar instrument, either a dollar at a US bank like a correspondent bank, and that's going to actually tie into the second question, or like a T bill of a very short maturity. And so you know, you could still have lots of
dollar based banking globally. You wouldn't be getting rid of global dollar. You would be stabilizing the global dollar by going to full reserve banking for the global dollar. There would be no money creation outside of the US. The expansion of the dollar money supply would happen by US domestic banks, but dollars could be held by say, Japanese banks, as long as it was on a one to one basis. And I think that would be the optimal answer, and we could talk about why, but you don't have to
go all the way to that. You could allow some dollar money creation outside of the US, but subjected to some type of US based oversight and regulation to have congruence between the domestic dollar money creation regulatory scheme and the overseas dollar money creation regulatory scheme. What makes the current system so unstable and difficult to govern is there is no congruence, and in fact there can be racis to the bottom dynamics and even worse right now, there's
so much opacity. You know, I said thirteen trillion dollars, but we don't really know the figure because there's no systematized reporting in the US. All of the banks file reports quarterly with their balance sheet information, and we can track the amount of dollar deposits. We actually cannot track the amount of deposit like liabilities being created offshore because there is there is no international agreement by which that information is reported to US authorities, and that would seem
to me to be like low hanging fruit. You don't have to get rid of the ability of banks in Japan and Europe to create dollars. Why don't we just make them tell us how many they're creating, and just some information about the assets on the other side of those balance sheets.
One of the really interesting things here is, as you just mentioned, euro dollars basically mean that banks outside of the US can create dollars, which you would think would
impinge on US monetary sovereignty. I mean it does, but at the same time, the existence of euro dollars combined with the dollar swaps, which you know, basically make them, as you were saying, a more attractive product to people to use, has solidified the dollar's role in the global financial system, like it has helped the dollar achieve and maintain reserve status. So, oh, you're shaking your head.
Okay, yeah, I think it's not it's it's definitely that's conventional wisdom.
Okay, all right, So there's nothing wrong with the I'm just to be conventional. But the question I was going to ask is if you had additional oversight of the market, would that start to dent the dollar's role given that there are concerns over you know, the US going too far on sanctions and things like that.
I think you're asking a very important question, and I want to try to unpack it a little bit because when I was calling conventional wisdom, I think jumbles up a lot of issues and it's understandable that they got jumbled up. But really to explain what the stakes are of the basil four type of response I was just describing, we really have to unjumple them. So those first, there's
the role of the dollar as a reserve currency. This is really quite distinct from euro dollars, which are the creation of US dollar money offshore by offshore financial situtions. We're going to connect it back a little bit, but the dollar's roles of reserve currency. What that's directly about is the fact that foreign central banks hold treasury securities as their reserve assets. It's not about using the dollar to transact or to finance trade, although those are also related.
It's about the fact that the Chinese, for example, have huge reserves and they have to invest those reserves, and they have chosen to invest a very large percentage of them in treasuries. So dollar as reserve currency means foreign central banks hold reserves in treasuries, and they have chosen treasuries for lots of reasons, having very little to do with certainly whether they're their domestic financial institutions have the ability to create dollar deposit liabilities versus have to hold
one to one balances with US banks. But also even that has little to do with whether dollars are being used to finance trade or settle international transactions. If you are a central bank and you have a very very large amount of reserves, let's say a couple trillion dollars, what assets are you going to put it in? And the choice to invest in treasuries has a lot more to do with US economic hegemony and the sheer, enormous quantity of US treasureies, then it has to do with
what currency is being used to globally trade. So China, for example, has you know, historically held lots of US treasuries. It's really hard to think that it has anything to do with the euro dollar market, which is really not something that is benefiting in any meaningful sense the Chinese.
What does relate to this sort of dollar as a you know, reserve currency for foreign central banks is the liquidity of treasury markets, of course, and one reason why you know, Saudi's or the Chinese would want to hold their reserves in treasuries is that they can bind sell very very easily with very low cost. That is a shadow banking story in part about the creation of the repo market and treasury repo which is a way to subsidize liquidity and treasury markets. But that's not a euro
dollar shadow banking story. That the repo shadow banking story. Okay, So the first point is if you change the rules on how banks in Japan and London hold dollar balances and you make them fully reserved. Is China going to decide they want to hold euros instead of treasuries. That's I find really really sort of hard to substantially. It just doesn't really connect. So does that mean it has nothing to do with it? No, So the global dollar is more than just a reserve currency. It's also a
currency of international trade and international finance. And so there's lots of trade between third countries that doesn't involve the United States where they use dollars to transact. That's the means of exchange. And because that's the means of exchange, it's also the lending currency associated with financing that exchange. And so we have this dollar financial system that's quite
a bit distinct from dollars reserve currency. You know, Chinese Central Bank wants to hold treasuries, has a bunch of reasons for that, totally different calculus for why Indian conglomerate wants to sell its products to South American country in dollars.
Different calculus. And with that second calculus, the euro dollars fit in a bit more, a bit more, because what's going on there is the Indian company has a bank, and the South American company has a bank, and in all likelihood their primary banks are not US based, and those banks would like to be able to create dollars, lend them in dollars, and not have to look to US banks for that liquidity. And so what the urinal system is really doing is cutting foreign financial institutions into
the profits of dollars seniorage. They're giving them a piece of the action, and they're giving them a reason to
want to be in the dollar business. And the way the whole thing got going initially was a lot of London banks wanted to get into the dollar business and we let them in basically, and that makes them evangelists for dollar based finance, as opposed to constantly trying to say to their clients, you know what, let's do this deal in pounds, because we create pounds, and if we had to do this deal in dollars, then we're gonna have to go borrow from City Group the dollars that
we need because we can't just create them ourselves. And there's not this whole euro dollar market for us. We got to go to the domestic US dollar market, and so we would have all these foreign financial institutions trying to suggest other currencies for international trade and financing and not being as gung ho about the dollar, which is not to say that they would necessarily succeed in convincing
the vast majority of their clients to change currencies. There's a lot of reasons why you would just you know, open up a bank account with a US based bank shift your business there. At the same time, the US has gotten very far in embedding and entrenching the dollar by building this coalition of global financial institutions that all are able to profit and benefit off of being in the dollar, as opposed to trying to keep all of those benefits onshore for US based banks.
So, just to further understand this point with a concrete example, one thing that's gotten attention recently is China building out a swap network, and I have seen that couched. As you know, China takes on the US dollar and that sort of thing. What do you think they're trying to do in that context?
So, as it turns out, China swap lines are just totally different from the FED swap lines, and so the Chinese are interested in spreading use of the RMB. They want other countries to use the RMB in trade, especially with China. They would be thrilled if the Indian company wanted to sell to the South American company and denominated an RMB. It's swap lines, though, are not trying to achieve that in anything like the way that the FED
swap lines are facilitating dollar money creation. The Chinese swap lines are basically a central bank lending program for indebted foreign governments, and so it's like World Bank or IMF loans, and so like a major borrower is Pakistan. Pakistan has had a swapline with the People's Bank of China.
Sounds like an outcrop of Belton Road.
It is an outcrop of Belton Road. It's exactly an outcrop of Belton Road. And in the US we would just never do that type of lending through our central bank. We did do something like that for Mexico in nineteen ninety five twenty billion dollar loan that came from the Treasury Department. That's like what the PBOC is doing, and they might have some sort of regulatory reasons. One thing that happens if you do it through your central bank is don't you don't report it? As sovereign lending to
like the World Bank. So it's it's much harder for international observers to keep track of how much Pakistan and Mongolia and these various recipients of PBOC swap line lending, how much they are actually occurring. It's less reported than maybe if the Chinese did it in a more official channel. But it's nothing like what the FED swap lines are. There's over thirty billion dollars right now of PBOC swap line outstanding. There's like basically zero of the FED swap lines.
It's you know, the PBOC is like an ongoing lending program.
Got it.
It's structured to look like it's not, but it is. That's what it is.
So the other thing I wanted to ask is you compare the size of the euro dollar market to tether basically throughout the podcast to describe how it's growing. Are stable coins the new euro dollar? I mean they kind of serve they seem to serve a similar purpose, and they seem to be similar things in the sense that their dollar denominated liabilities.
Stable coins definitely have the potential to be the new euro dollar. Tether in particular, has a lot of Euro dollar flavor to it, but there are really important differences. One is that tether is not being used to finance or settle international trade. The Indian company are not selling
to South American buyers or vice versa using tether. That's a Euro dollar system is tied to the real economy and real economic activity, and up until this point, the cryptocurrency space is very much looking at itself, and so tethers are used primarily to buy cryptocurrency, not to facilitate real economic activity, or they're used to conduct illicit transactions that are difficult to conduct in the FIAT regulated system. I did air quotes, but that doesn't come across in
this media. That said, tether has gotten huge and it is exploiting the same sort of regulatory loophole if the year dollar system is exploiting. The tether balances have a very similar economic status to the Euro dollar balances. And one could imagine, insofar as tether is legitimated in some sense and it takes on greater scale, that it could expand its role and sort of jump over. You get out of just the crypto ecosystem and get into the real economic activity and be a real competitor with other
dollar money forms. It certainly is a dollar money form, and it could be a it could be a competitor in certain transactions for certain purposes.
So there is a sense of multilateralism at play with the entire year, the development of the eurodollar market, certainly and the swap lines. And I guess I'm wondering, with the new Trump administration coming in, is there any sense that those swap lines could could be maybe not as reliable as they were under previous administrations.
Absolutely, and I think this is something that's probably not
getting talked about. The whole swap line based euro dollar system is very much a product of a particular geopolitical diplomatic arrangement between the United States and a variety of allies and partners that involves a certain orientation to those allies and partners, where the US is basically making an ongoing commitment over a long period of time that it will be there to provide in essence, discount window like backing to the extent that the US is incapable of
making those types of long term commitments or everything is going to be hashed out on a case by case basis.
And that's the new sort of international multilateral paradigm that's deeply destabilizing for the year dollar market, and to the extent questions would be raised about whether certain countries would be able to actually draw on their swap lines that could lead to runs and panics, just in the way that in nineteen thirty two and nineteen thirty three there were runs and panics throughout the US banking system, in part because he wasn't clear the extent to which the
Federal Reserve was actually going to be there with discount window lending to backstop those entities.
I think we've learned a lot more about the euro dollar market, including why it is not the euro dollar exchange rate. Do you feel like, no that I get that that's been hammered into your ear?
Ye know that, I know.
I knew that before that.
I do you have admitted to not knowing that at one point I didn't know that? Yeah, Okay. Lots More is produced by Carmen Rodriguez and Dashell Bennett, with help from Moses onom and Cal Brooks.
Our sound engineer is Blake Maples. Sage Bouman is the head of Bloomberg Podcasts.
Please rate, review, and subscribe to Odd Lots and lots more on your favorite podcast platforms.
And remember the Bloombergs Subscribers can listen to all of our podcasts add free by connecting through Apple Podcasts. Thanks for listening.