From New York Times Opinion, this is the Ezra Klein Show. I don't know if y'all were fans growing up of the show The Jetsons, but if you were and if you were super fan enough to take the internal math of the show seriously, George Jetson was supposed to have been born in 2022. He would be a toddler right now. And the world we live in, the world my toddler is growing up in, it does not feel like it is a world on path to the future of the Jetsons imagined.
A future that a lot of people in the 1960s thought was totally plausible by the 20, 20, 20, 20, 30s, 20, 40s, 20, 50s. So what happened that got us off of that track, not just the real track but the imaginary track? Another way of asking this question, a question that has come up a lot in the book I'm writing about how liberalism changed and why it's become so difficult to build is what happened in the 1970s?
The 70s are this break point, between one era in our economy and our government, our society, and our vision for the future, and the next. The 70s are when economic inequality really begins rising, when the environmental movement takes off when a huge amount of legislation is passed in response to the harms of all the building and growth that it happened since a new deal.
But there's this tendency to look at the places that legislation goes too far and to say, well, if we hadn't made all these dumb mistakes, everything would be great. We'd be richer, we'd have our moon colonies, our flying cars, and our nuclear energy, we would have made it to Jetsons land. But then why do you know other countries take that path to just wipe away the politics and the passions that led to the backlash against certain forms of growth and technology in a lot of different countries?
Is to miss something important, something that anybody who cares about growth is going to need to understand if we're not just going to repeat the mistakes of the past? Jim Pethikukis is a senior fellow at the Conservative American Enterprise Institute. He's the author of the Technology Focus Substack, Faster Please, and of the recent book, The Conservative Futurist.
And one thing I've noticed is there are ways in which I feel like he and I are asking a lot of the same questions, but from very different ideological positions. So I want to see where our stories converge and where they differ and what happened to the world of the Jetsons. As always, my email is reclineshow at nwytimes.com. Jim Pethikukis, welcome to the show. Thanks so much for having me on. So I'm going to begin this conversation in the early 70s.
Things change in the US economy on any number of charts you begin to see something happen to the line. What are some of those changes? The most obvious change, and especially from an economics point of view, is that the sort of rapid productivity growth that we saw in the previous couple of decades, that economists and other experts in the 60s thought was going to be a permanent state of affairs slowed down. And other than really the late 90s, early 2000s, it's been in that sort of weaker state.
And it's one of the great still conundrums for economists. I mean, economists still, less so now, would have the base about what caused the great depression. And to me, this downshift, where I call them, I look at the great downshift and productivity growth, is as significant as that because of we are not where we could be if it hadn't. So if it had kept growing since the 70s, as it did in the couple decades before, what would the US economy look like?
What would the median household income look like? Bigger, more, multiples more. And that was the expectation. So instead of having a $25 trillion economy, depending on how you want to slice the numbers, it could be twice as big. It could be three times as big. So I don't know. I think conservatively, instead of like the median family making $80,000 adjusted for inflation, maybe they make $150,000. It's pretty significant. What that economy would look like?
Well, listen, to grow that fast, it would be driven by technological growth. And that's what people expected in those immediate post-war decades. So all the sort of the kind of classic retro jatsons kind of sci-fi things that people imagined back then, it wasn't just sort of cartoons and films, experts, technologists, CEOs, economists, all expected. That kind of stuff actually happened. So nuclear power and everything, nuclear reactors from coast to coast.
We would probably have, you know, colonies on the moon and Mars cures to diseases which see my crop diseases, which we still battle would be cured. All of that together would be part of sort of this grand future driven by rapid technological progress, which drives faster productivity growth, which drives faster economic growth. There's one last of the pandemic is people don't like suffering and shortages. So we better figure out a different way.
I see the only path forward is through growth and technology and making that work. What is your theory, though, of what happened in the 70s? What do you see as the contributors to this slowdown? I think certainly is probably multi-cozel. One reason I wrote the book, to be honest, is a paper. A paper by an economist named Ray Fair from Yale University who noticed something weird happened around the 70s.
He wasn't focused on productivity growth, but he looked at infrastructure spending as a share of total economic spending. And he looked at what was going on with the budget where we started to begin to run smaller surpluses and run budget deficits around 1970. And he asked the exact same question that you're asking. So what happened? Because from those two statistics, he began to wonder like, that to me seems like a society that's less future-oriented than it used to be.
You tended to see it more in the United States than in other places. So what are your theories? Listen, I'm not going to create a brand new theory, was just that all the great inventions, the internal combustion engine, electrification of factories, and came all those great inventions of the second kind of phase in dusher revolution, we'd kind of squeezed all the sort of productivity gains out of those and they weren't replaced by another wave of great inventions. I mean, that's a theory.
I mean, another theory is just that as we've advanced in science technology, it's just harder to kind that tree of knowledge and come up with more big ideas and requires more people and resources. All of that is probably true. But like, our decisions mattered. And there are things that we did which hurt and I hope we can reverse some of those things because that would help.
And I think the two, I think, screamingly obvious things that we stopped doing is we stop spending on science, research, and development the way we did in the 1960s. And we began to regulate our economy as if regulation would have no impact on innovation. What's your causal theory of why we did that? I think a lot of that was because of NASA and we won the space race and there just wasn't an interest in continuing that. Okay, so that's sort of the immediate short term explanation.
So much of that was really just NASA because I think of the R&D surge as the Cold War. And the Soviet Union was going strong in the 70s. Right, Soviet Union was going strong, but we had clearly won that space race. And while we've continued to spend a lot of money on R&D as a share of the economy, it's a lot less than what it used to be. That's not surprising that perhaps there was a shift in priorities. So they begin worrying about budgets back then.
And the regulation part to me also sort of isn't surprising when countries become wealthier. They tend to care a lot more about the downsides of economic growth, their books like Silent Spring and some events like the Santa Barbara Oil Film. We began learning more about the radiation from Hiroshima and all and worrying about nuclear. So that is not surprising that we started to pass environmental regulation.
What is surprising is that when it became clear that the economy was not re-accelerating the way they thought that there was not more of sort of a holistic effort to change that, to not give up on those expectations that people had in the 1960s. So I've been for my own book thinking a lot about the 70s and looking a lot at the politics of the 70s. And from where we sit now, we think of environmentalism as a liberal thing, right? The environmentalists are greens, they're Democrats.
And I ran into this quote that Richard Nixon gives in his 1970s state of the Union that I think gives a good flavor of how different the politics have become. So I want to play that here. The great question of the 70s is, shall we surrender to our surroundings? Or shall we make our peace with nature and begin to make reparations for the damage we have done to our air, to our land, and to our water? Restoring nature to its natural state is a cause beyond party and beyond factions.
It has become a common cause of all the people of this country. It is a cause of particular concern to young Americans because they, more than we, will reap the grim consequences of our failure to act on programs which are needed now if we are to prevent disaster later. Clean air, clean water, open spaces, these should once again be the birthright of every American. If we act now, they can do. We still think of air as free, but clean air is not free. And neither is clean water.
The price tag and pollution control is high. Through our years of past carelessness, we incurred a debt to nature and now that debt is being called. What do you think when you hear that?
I think that's exactly what I would expect to hear for a country that has gone through a period of industrialization and economic growth where people had become rich enough that the immediate sort of material concerns could be balanced off with other kinds of concerns such as the water they're drinking, the air we're breathing, is it worth losing a little bit of growth maybe to deal with that? So that doesn't surprise me.
And as you know, some of the key environmental legislation, we still have happened under the Nixon administration. A huge amount of it. I mean, I think you can make a very good case. And it's the most consequential environmentalist president of the 20th century. But did people back then assume that what they were doing with that environmental legislation was making it very difficult to build the kind of future they had imagined heading into the 1970s? I don't think they did.
I believe they thought that the economy was so strong and that technological progress, the momentum was so tremendous that we could have cleaner air and water and still have everything else. The people who voted for French and the National Environmental Policy Act, most people thought that was just kind of like a good mom and pop and baseball and apple pie piece of legislation. Hey, who doesn't want cleaner water? That's all what we're doing here.
I don't think anyone imagined that then it would make it hard to build a factory that makes wind turbines in the year 2024. Well, what's the evidence that that raft of environmental legislation, the National Environmental Policy Act, you mentioned, you know, the Endangered Species Act, we have Clean Air Acts, Clean Water Acts. A lot of them work really well. We really do clean up the air, the water. I mean, I grew up in Los Angeles or outside Los Angeles.
The smog is much better today than when I was growing up. You can see them out in some time. You can see them out in some time. What is the evidence that that is as causal in the so-down of productivity as you're putting it here? After the space age, after Apollo, we didn't follow it with anything, right? One thing we Nixon thought about following it with was building nuclear reactors, a thousand nuclear reactors from coast to coast.
What had been possible to build a thousand nuclear reactors from coast to coast with the emerging regulatory regime that was beginning to happen? Absolutely not. And it became obvious, even in the early 70s, that there was a problem, that there was a problem that was becoming harder to build. That was the case with the Alaska Pipeline.
It became, again, you're too young to remember this, but it was a running joke in the United States in the 1970s that they could not build a new dam in Tennessee because of a tiny little fish called the snail darder. And that fish was preventing that fish that no one could barely see it. Nobody knew about it. We couldn't build that dam because that was an endangered species act.
I think the weight of those kind of incidents, the weight of the academic studies I cite in my book, have there been studies looking at how much it costs to build a highway and does NEPA, the National Environmental Policy Act, does it make it more expensive? Does it make it harder to build?
Yes. And I think if you just look around right now, I don't think it's a tremendous leap of imagination to think that if it makes it very difficult to build a transmission line, a nuclear power plant, where are the nuclear power plants? I mean, it's like the dog that did invite. Where are they? So let's talk about nuclear here because nuclear is interesting to me because I basically agree with you. Do you not think that NEPA had a material impact?
I don't think there's any doubt that the totality of environmental and regulatory bills passed in the 70s, slows growth or a different way to put it is makes it hard to build. I mean, it's a big part of the work I'm doing right now. At the same time, when you're trying to measure or try to understand what has happened to a total factor productivity, I think this case is a little harder to make than people want it to be for a couple of reasons. But I'll give you one here. Let's take nuclear.
I am 100% on board with the idea that we've made it much too hard to build and iterate nuclear technology in this country. On the other hand, there is no country anywhere that is living in the nuclear topia that nuclear advocates are always telling me was possible. There are countries that use much more nuclear energy than we do, France being a great example, but France does not have energy to cheap to meter. They do not have a wild level of energy abundance.
There is something here where one of the ways this sounds and it sounds as if I didn't move on to read your book, is that there's been this 20 or maybe 1000 or maybe trillion or maybe multi trillion dollar bill lying on the sidewalk. And you would expect some country to pick it up. But you know, you go from the 70s forward, nobody today is ahead of America.
It sort of doesn't surprise me that countries, which I think have been over these decades, far less innovative and pushing forward the technological frontier might not be pushing forward the technology of nuclear power. So why doesn't France have very cheap nuclear energy? Why doesn't France already have these very small nuclear reactors? I'm not sure what the incentive was or whether they were capable of innovating to that degree. I don't know.
But the incentive is exactly what you're saying, right? I mean, it's not a market based power system in France. These are all state subsidized reactors. I mean, it takes South Korea, take the UAE, take China. I mean, you can pick your country here. The kind of question I'm trying to raise about your thesis because it's also relevant frankly to my thesis is if the problem is that America makes a series of policy mistakes in the 70s.
Why then in the ensuing five decades don't a bunch of our competitor countries race past us? There were theories that they would Japan in the 80s and 90s seemed like maybe they were. Right? Japan was going to be the future. There are a million books written in the 90s about this Germany at different times, right? But I don't think you would look at anybody today. Many rich countries of significant size and say they really got it right and we really got it wrong.
So how do you understand that if the story is about mistakes we specifically made in the 70s? Well, we can make mistakes that are very specific to us and other countries may have made different mistakes. Even though there was, as you say, this great enthusiasm in the 80s that Japan had it sort of figured out that they could do economic growth and innovation in a brand new way would turn out not to be the case. And then you mentioned Germany.
We seem to have this insatiable desire to find some people do to find some other model. I don't think those models have turned out better than the American model. If you were to try to make an argument about why things look not the same but why nobody has achieved the Jim Pathakukus world across Canada, across Western Europe, across Asia, right? All countries during this period that were rich enough to do much of what you're talking about. Do you have theories that unite the answer?
Yeah, I mean, I don't think it is wrong to do sort of a cross country because this productivity slowdown didn't just happen in the United States. Not clearly there were some sort of macro reasons. It just becoming harder and more expensive to do research. Those things affected everybody. So once you've assumed, okay, there was this umbrella effect that would sort of make difficult to do productivity and economic growth and faster tech progress everywhere. So that mattered.
And then to what extent do our decisions matter? At first, we didn't understand what happened. And then when we did, I think we just underestimated the difficulty. At least certainly in the United States of returning to fast growth. And the ideas that we put forward, whether it was a little more spending on this program, a tax cut here, maybe those are individually great ideas. But given, I think the headwinds from these macro factors, sort of the tailwinds need to be much, much stronger.
And even now when we're talking about spending more money on R&D, I don't think it's enough. Let me try some thesis on you that I think can work across countries. One is that as countries get richer, they become more risk-averse. Some of the innovations you're talking about, like colonies on the moon and flying cars, they require a high tolerance for risk. Maybe as societies get more affluent. People have enough, their lives are good enough. They aren't as motivated to take that risk.
But do you think of that? I think inherently people pull back from risk. To go back to the 70s, there are some conservative thinkers who thought that capitalism was doomed because the intellectuals who were separated from the actually working and producing wouldn't appreciate how hard it is to do that. They want to appreciate how hard it is actually to grow an economy. These people who would be our bureaucrats, and they'd be focused on risk aversion and creating more rules.
So yeah, I think that's an obvious problem. Then add in the fact that as countries get richer, they care more about the environment. You see it in China. As China's gotten richer, they care more about smog. For people to move beyond that inherent caution, they have to believe it is worth it. People need a realistic plausible image of why it's all worth it. We used to have people who would do that for us.
We had a public intellectuals and we had Hollywood who would say, the future can be better and it's going to be awesome and then that disappear. So who paints a future? Listen, I used to spend a lot of time going on like the Drudge Report. It's still operating. I don't think it is what it used to be.
Every article about technology and science and Silicon Valley was, these are crazy people who want a future and inhuman future for you where you're going to all live in tubes and you're going to all have bugs, bugs for you. No more stakes or I'm going to have like bug stakes. That's just one small example and I can point to pretty much every Hollywood film in the past 50 years. So what is our sort of collective imagination of why are we going to do this?
That we don't live in a world that's destined to burn. That we don't live in a world where if we should have all these wonderful inventions, only the people at the very rich will have it. They'll be living above us on the space platforms while everybody on earth is groveling around. We don't have this inability to say like, why should you take our risk? And that has to change. I think visions of the future, to degree people don't always appreciate or built on what people see in the present.
And something that has been striking to me, as I've done a lot of research into the politics of the 60s and 70s, is how much people ceased liking what they saw in the present. I don't play a speech that Lyndon Johnson gave in 1964 talking about what America looked like to him in terms of not how I think of the great society. The water we drink, the food we eat, the very air that we breathe are threatened with pollution. Our parks are overcrowded, our seashores overburdened.
Green fields and dense forests are disappearing. A few years ago we were greatly concerned about the ugly American. Today we must act to prevent an ugly America. So one thing that I think, or I've come to believe, is a bigger dimension here, is that beauty is part of politics. And wanting a beautiful world believing that you're going to get a beautiful world matters, this is part of post materialist politics, which are very, very powerful and begin, I think, strongly in the 60s and the 70s.
So how do you think about that dimension of it, the kind of pervasiveness of a fear, that the modernity people were getting from rapid growth, was an ugly, advertising-soaked, concrete, gray, deforested, modernity? Was that the majority opinion? Do you think that people thought there was too much affluence? And beauty, again, that's a preference.
Some people of this notion of solar punk, we're all going to live in sort of these giant trees, or part tree, but you have to, even skyscrapers will be gardens. That is a personal preference for a kind of world. I'm sure, I think we're maybe taking our views now, we're kind of being posing on what people thought in the 60s based on one speech. No, so that I can assure you I'm not doing.
I'm just not yet reading you, chapter one and two of my forthcoming thoughts on the chapter, they're excellent. They're glittering. But this politics was pervasive. I mean, there are all kinds of books written about this. I mean, this is what the environmental movement comes out of. The environmental movement is not built on climate change. It's built on conservation of green space. And the silenced spring and the recession. And I think that's legitimate.
And I want to push you on this because this thing that I hear you doing is wiping this to the side. That's a personal preference. But what we're trying to do here, what I'm trying to do with you, there's plenty things you and I disagree on. You're conservative. I'm a progressive. But one thing that I don't think we disagree on is that we're not building enough and productivity is too low. But what I want to try to understand is, well, then why and why is it happening in so many places?
And one theory that I take very seriously now, having looked at the politics, right? Kiki Taki. That's a term that comes from a song recorded about what the homes look like in Daily City in California. Little boxes on the whole song, little boxes made up Kiki Taki little boxes on the whole song, little boxes all the same. There's a pink one and a green one and a blue one.
I can show you pieces written in the San Francisco Chronicle where they talk about the people moving to California like locusts, right? Like they're going to just destroy the thing. And I agree that beauty is in the eye of the beholder. But often the politically powerful beholders are the ones who live in a place already. So for instance, one kind of curb on productivity that I believe is really important is the inability to build homes in highly productive places like cities.
You bring this up in your book too. But the people of power there, they like the way it looks now. They like the brown stones. They don't want to see those knocked over for big apartment buildings. So I agree with you, right? You find beautiful what I find beautiful with another person finds beautiful. They might all be different. But one thing that I wonder is, do you just discount the power of people's aesthetic preference in politics?
Is it a story of aesthetics or is it a story of a generation sort of repulsed by their parents? I guarantee the parents in those Tiki Taki houses probably thought those are pretty good houses, probably better houses than what they grew up on. So what they lose in politics, what I, well, because that generation was really, really big and eventually that generation took control. But okay, get to where it gets your question. What is the future going to look like?
I could point to some possibilities. And I could maybe, I would love if sort of science fiction people and their people in science fiction who think that as well, that they need to create images that aren't utterly dystopian. Like that's an entire movement within that community. Like, I wouldn't say like, that's my image of the future. I want to give people like the tools and make sure the economy is growing. And then we can all kind of create the future we want.
But I don't think it needs to be one particular preference. It needs to be like a solar punk vision or some other kinds of vision. Well, I'm not, I'm not saying you have to show this. I'm not saying we should impose one one aesthetic. But what I am saying is that I think there's good reason to believe that this huge generation you're bringing up right, you know, and I take that point that the boomer generation is large.
They don't like what they saw and that that happened in a lot of different places at once. I mean, I have a million problems politically, as you might imagine, with Elon Musk, just like a million problems. One reason that guy has been a very successful futurist is that he takes beauty very seriously. You can go less controversial. You could say Steve Jobs, who took how things look at the elegance. I mean, he's a boomer and he wanted to create beautiful, elegant products.
Now how you translate that to a public policy that creates a beautiful, elegant future. But I think Elon Musk, to some degree, has that. I mean, who wants to go to Mars? Really? It's cold. There's no air. There's nobody there. But SpaceX has created these marvelous little videos about what it would be like to get out of Starship's spaceship.
And if you get to Mars and see these beautiful kind of domes and it's green, and that's an elegant, beautiful vision of future for a place that's none of those things. One thing when I think about the sort of conservatism in your futurism that actually surprised me in your book was the confidence that if we pumped a bunch more money into the R&D structure, we would get a bunch more output. I hope. I'm confident about that at least on even days.
Well let me, one counterargument on this, I hear sometimes, right? As you mentioned, a lot of the R&D surge mid-century came from NASA. And when you think about the amount of money NASA's had to spend on R&D in recent decades, and the amount of money SpaceX had to spend on R&D, which of course SpaceX could only do that because of NASA contracts, but nevertheless they had less money. And how fast SpaceX was actually able to advance rocket technology.
I think it should make you wonder why NASA is not as able to make advances as it once was. I think you could say this across a lot of domains of federally funded, government funded R&D. So I think there is a question of how much money there is, and there's also a question of whether the structure support that money turning into innovations, turning into products. How do you think about that? Well I mean, I think the people at SpaceX would say that they stand on the shoulders of giants.
So they did not have to start at a baseline at zero and figure out how to get something into space. So I think that's important to note. I would like the government spending more money on R&D. I think I would like a hard look at what they call the meta-science, which is how is that money actually spent? What is that process like? Our good ideas squashed. This is sort of an emerging area of public policy where they're taking a hard look at that process.
Our good controversial ideas, are they not getting funded? Like those kinds of reforms, I think would have to be part of anything. And I'm not sure that spending more, I mean, great, I can point to studies, but until we actually do it, I don't know. But I think we're at sort of like a moment that we should try to use every plausible idea to make sure we don't waste a moment that I think we had at the end of the 60s.
But I think we had at the end of the 90s to create a much faster growing economy. We have this emerging cluster of technologies that support these technologies. And I think AI is a great example and see if like this is possible because I've lived through 50 years of what some people call the great stagnation, the book I call the great challenge. I don't want that to be the next 50 years because what does our politics look like after the past decade of economic commotion stagnation?
I don't want to look at our politics after another decade of that. Let's talk about a success story of innovations of the government, which is DARPA. What makes DARPA work? And is that scalable? Well, you mean, you have highly motivated people working on very specific projects, the managers of those programs are not there forever. Like they're there to create new technologies that would have some sort of military application. So like the easy answer is we need DARPA for everything.
We need to have this. Can you scale that? I would like, geez, I would like to try. I would like to try scaling that. I would try scaling a lot of things. I think it shows that despite skepticism that can't accomplish anything, you can point to the successes of DARPA. How do you think about tolerance for failure? Because one thing DARPA has is a tolerance for failure. I think part of that is that it's understood and has been a sort of part of the national security state.
And we allow the national security state to waste money. We're cool that the fact that some things are not going to work out, we don't get mad at them. On the other hand, when you have the Department of Energy, give out a loan to something like Selindra that doesn't come through, there is their hearings. There's a scandal. People are furious. I mean, that same program also saved Tesla, which is something you hear less about.
So what allows things in government to make counterintuitive bets and what allows them to survive those bets failing? When Selindra happened, there was a sort of a deep skepticism that the era of the clents of the Arab big government is over. And now it seemed like the era of big government was back. And I think people were waiting to pounce on that. I mean, I looked at Selindra and my immediate thought was, this is back then, like this is government failing again.
So I don't think I had that kind of tolerance for failure. I sort of do now. My personal tolerance is higher. I don't think for most people in the right right now is yet particularly high, if you're looking at it purely in a political standpoint. Listen, and I'm sure you're aware of this, that like in the past, when there have been these government science programs that have been conservatives who have picked through them to try to find something that sounds like ridiculous or silly.
You're correct. Yes, but ridiculous or silly. Like, why are we spending money to figure out like how hamsters survive an orbit or something like that? So we shouldn't pretend not to have a toleration of basic science because even the kinds of basic science that didn't seem like it had any application, like I don't know, the theory of relativity is why we have GPS. But this seems like an important reformist project on, in your coalition, I mean, you work at the American Enterprise Institute.
That is the kind of place that has made this argument. Right, year after year after year after year. And it probably makes it against Democrats, right? I mean, Selendra, I don't think Selendra was the issue there. Was it you were in a kind of post-Bill Clinton turn against neoliberalism? It was that you could make a Democratic president look really bad, right? And you could make the stimulus look bad.
And to me, when I think of why I am nervous as a liberal, that if I pump, we pump a huge amount of money into government R&D, we're not going to get the kind of fundamental advances that I'm hoping for. It's that I think a lot of the major government research structures have now been built to emphasize a kind of conservatism, not a conservatism of the political sort, but conservatism of the, we don't want to spend money on anything that could make us look bad sort.
And so there's a lot of peer review. There's a lot of bureaucracy. There's a lot of people checking your work. The grant operations are huge. And the amount of time people spend checking grants, there's a big cover your ass mentality. And the problem with that is, I think actually a bipartisan problem. Like on the one hand, I think liberals are too trusting of process. I think liberals have become just a kind of process obsessed institutional defenders.
But I think conservatives have in some ways created a bunch of that because they've created the conditions in which people in government and particularly civil servants are terrified of being the ones to have done something that gets their agency embarrassed and their funding cut. And so I'm curious when you think about this as a reformist project in your own coalition, how do you think about that?
So I was listening to the podcast you did fairly recently, which was some demsus and thinking about some of these issues of zoning, housing restrictions and why it's hard to build anything. And housing actually is the perfect issue. Things seems like we need more housing and conservatives should like that growth and we're conservative, supposed to like economic growth and tumult and dynamism and people can move to high productivity cities, but conservatives seem to be against housing reform.
At least some conservatives, they don't like the idea because if you had as a culture issue, which eventually eats up everything because you're destroying the suburbs, you're going to bring the wrong kind of people to our neighborhood and all that kind of thing. So the people who are on the left who are looking at these issues. And think we need maybe need to grow faster and there's things we need to build in this country and maybe regulations are a problem and you know, funding is a problem.
There needs to be an ally on the right where you're certainly not going to agree on everything, but like there's a common ground with people who have some sort of confidence that we can actually move forward on problems. But right now, I think while there are some pockets of that, I think on the right and the Republican Party, it just seems to be sort of more abundant at the moment.
The one of these that blows my mind is I am not a person inclined to give Donald Trump huge amounts of credit, but Operation Warp Speed is one of the most successful government programs ever. Full stop. It is just like a tremendous astounding success. Is he running on eight or ten more Operation Warp Speed? No, is or Republican Party proposing a bunch more Operation Warp Speed for other kinds of things as far as I can tell no. By the way, the Democrats aren't either.
I've talked to them about why and I kind of get the sense it has something to do with whether or not, you know, they want to give Donald Trump credit for things, but here you have just an astonishing, like a truly astonishing policy success. We were able to pull forward a completely futuristic technology in a timeframe nobody thought possible and make it available for free to Americans, right? Like it was equitable. It was technological. We worked with a private sector.
The public sector got things out of their way and it is an orphan and the political economy of Warp Speed's orphan status is I think one in indictment of American politics, but too, also a bit of a genuine mystery because here, you know, Donald Trump could run on this. Like it was a success of his presidency. Nothing crickets. Why? My hope has been and as you just suggested it has yet to be realized that the pandemic would accelerate this need.
I would hope to accelerate technological progress in growth. There's a perfect example of a problem that many people knew was coming, right? I mean, there's a gazillion white papers that we're going to have a pandemic. But yet despite that fact, we didn't have enough ventilators and we didn't have enough masks.
And what finally, despite all the white papers, all the thoughts about preparation, what finally really allowed our economy and our lives to go on was the fact that America's a really rich country and were really technologically advanced.
And we were able to solve a problem on the fly because of those two things and that people will look at that example and we no longer have to go back to Apollo to be excited about something where like we all came together and solved the big problem beating the Russians. This time we all came together and solved the big problem and people have yet to look at that. Instead, it has sort of gotten lost. And I can blame Donald Trump for that for not talking about that.
Like he should be talking about that and if he's not going to talk about it, I would love for Democrats to talk about it and use that as an example. But I hope that eventually we'll be able to look at the pandemic, Operation Warp speed as sort of proof of concept that all of the things we've been talking about can work. One of the things that has been surprising to me in post-pandemic politics and policy is we've spent a lot of money since 2021.
We spent money on kind of stimulus for the economy, support for the economy. We spent money on certain kinds of pandemic preparedness. The thing we've not really spent money on is vaccines. We have not put together a huge new project to try to create vaccines across an array of different diseases. There's possibilities of pan-coronavirus vaccines. And I reported on a bunch of this and what I found was that there wasn't really a constituency for it.
You know, there were people in the Biden administration trying to get vaccine money into different kinds of bills. On the one hand, they weren't finding the votes, but on the other hand, the critique I would make of Joe Biden is it nor was he out there demanding it. They got me thinking about the way outside maybe climate, we underrate technological solutions to political problems.
One of the lines I have on this is that a liberal can typically tell you sort of five social insurance programs they would like to build on proof, right? Universal pre-K, single-payer healthcare, you know, you can pick your set. They typically can't tell you the five technologies. They want the government to pull forward into the present, right? The five technologies they really want to fund to try to make happen.
You right now a little bit around energy people can, but I think outside of that, it isn't a way people think about things. What is your answer to that? If the government was going to come out with its, these are the five technologies we are going to try to put money behind, clear bureaucratic roadblocks out of the way of, make sure you can have the materials for, like what is your, you know, your five technologies for social progress agenda?
I don't want to create like a China 2025 plan where we're going to pick a bunch of technologies and I do worry about being locked in a certain kind of technological path, which is why I do like basic research and I do like to see what the private sector is doing and try to support that, like with my example, about, you know, deep geothermal looks like it might be something, but they need more money for demonstration projects.
I think having some sort of, you know, impromptu that this is actually going to work and is making progress, I think government has a more of a role in that situation, but I'll tell you. I don't know if you recall, but last summer for about a week, there was this notion and I think it was a Korean researchers had figured out superconductivity that we could create these materials, which would allow us to transmit electricity with no loss.
And if that was possible, like everything was possible, like 90% of what Star Trek's about was possible, we could build very fast, very cheap high speed rails, brand new medical devices, and then it turned out that that's not the case. I'll have to admit, I thought hard, maybe we need a Manhattan project for superconductors, maybe that's something, all these problems we've been talking about, that kind of breakthrough would utterly change our entire sort of political discussion.
And AI that can be 80% as efficient as a human, we have a very different discussion. All of a sudden the economy can grow at a point and a half faster for extended period of time. Our entitlement discussion, our politics is completely different. So yeah, technology, driving progress, driving growth, it's a different kind of politics, and one where we're not fighting over a, you know, a fixed pie, but how to grow the economy faster.
But I think, and maybe this is the liberal versus in me versus a conservative in you, I think this is a bit of a dodge, because if you want to pump all this money into R&D, if you want to pump it all, even just into basic research, someone somewhere has to decide where this money is going, right?
I can imagine different ways you might do that, but for somebody has to decide how we are allocating this money, how much to what kind of scientists, but the government is to decide as you're client to govern this decide and people will have to make decisions, not against making decisions. I am against someone making a decision saying, this is the kind of engine we need to have for some of our hypersonic clients.
Well, I'm not saying that's what I'm asking, you know, about technologies, how we achieve the technologies, right? That, you know, I'm quite agnostic on that myself, but the other thing the government has to do, which I do think people really underestimate, is get difficulties out of the way.
So I remember when I was reporting on the effort to develop a pan-coronavirus vaccine, and I was talking to one lab that had a pretty promising candidate, and the genius vaccine expert leading that lab was spending so much of their time trying to source monkeys. They just couldn't get the monkeys they needed to run trials. And I remember just thinking, that should be somebody else's job, right?
This person who has got into this point in medical research that they're leading this lab and getting this funding to create a vaccine that could save however many lives, and no point in their career was their expertise, logistics or thing. But actually, everybody I talked to in this period was like, they're working on grants, they're trying to find these things.
And if you look at warp speed, a bunch of warp speed did was, you know, figure out how to get the correct materials so you could transport these vaccines, and, you know, they wouldn't break in transport, right? There's a lot of just making the jobs of scientists easier. There's a lot of the government acting as a kind of accelerator of innovation, but it does require the government to make decisions about where it's going to focus its efforts.
So then I'm going to go back to my question, which is after you've written this book, I mean, you read a substack about the future and about all these technologies. You don't have in the back of your head the five things you'd like to see a Manhattan project on a warp speed on again, to govern is to choose. Like what would you choose? What do you think would, if we really put our backs into it, it is possible for us to move forward into the present and would do the most good?
Yeah. I think one technology that if we're able to crack it and there's already money pouring into it is nuclear fusion. I don't think I've ever seen a cabinet officer happier than when energy department secretary Jennifer Granholm was talking about the nuclear fusion breakthrough about a year and a half ago. And like there's more work that needs to be done on that technology. I think government has a role.
I think a lot of these energy technologies, if you talk to these startups, I always ask I'm like, what do you want government to be doing? And of course, you know, we'll point to some regulation and I'll say, okay, that's great. Now, I'm not surprised that you said that. But what about is there some aspect of technology that needs more work? And they'll point to it. It could be like, you know, some sort of drill bit for geothermal.
But yeah, so I think broadly areas of I think energy, I'm sorry, for not just going to stop with energy because that just seems to be the linchpin. I mean, I'm very excited about artificial intelligence and what it can do. And it can be a general purpose technology that can help us, you know, do science better and come up with cures. But already you have people saying, oh, great, maybe it'll do all that, but we just can't afford the amount of power. How you get to power those data centers?
So if that's like the thing, if that's like a key constraint, artificial intelligence, yeah, then energy is pretty important and we better be doing more work. Again, I've we've mentioned nuclear fusion, but it might not be. Maybe it's not nuclear fusion. Maybe it is geothermal. And I'm glad we're going to space. I'm glad we're going to space because I love the space program. I love the idea of us doing things in orbit. But you know what?
Someday we may be able to use the materials from Mars to build space solar panels to beam the infinite amount of power to earth. So yeah, I think energy is certainly a sector that I would like to see more research done. And I think federal government has a role. How do you marry technology and sustainability?
This is something that I think discussions of technology often miss that there are values embedded in technologies, which technologies we pursue, which technologies we deploy, whether you leave everything in the market, whether you have a guiding hand of government, whether you're pricing carbon or not pricing carbon. How do you approach the process by which we make those decisions? You're often here now, what kind of is talking about AI and how will automate jobs.
And I say, well, we need the kind of AI that will create new things, but less of the kind that will automate people on jobs. So we need, you know, job creating kind of AI, but not sort of the job replacing kind of AI, which is, I think we probably need both. But I don't know of any real public policy that can do that. So to me, then, that's sort of, there's no remedy that's realist of that. So I'm not going to give that a lot of regard what we need is both.
And say like, well, I'm going to get a certain kind of outcome by tweaking the tax code in this way. Seems to me to be unrealistic. So I guess I'm skeptical about the guiding technology sort of path, I think you're suggesting. I don't think that's quite right. So let me give a very concrete example using AI as what we're talking about, you could make it possible to make a huge amount of money using AI to manipulate or persuade people to buy things, right? To hook AI into advertising.
You could also say, we are not going to allow you to hook AI into personalized database advertising, right? Those are both just choices as a society can make. You could say we're going to allow you to do it, but not for anybody under 18, right? I mean, there's a million things you can do here. And the path of AI development will be different depending on what kind of things you can do to make money with it.
If it turned out the government had a bunch of prizes out there where if you could use AI to achieve this or that scientific goal, you got $3 billion and the answer went into the public domain, people would build more AI's in that direction. So there are a lot of ways to shape the pathway of technology. I don't know that we can say we're going to have the good kind of AI and not the bad kind of AI. But the decisions we make about how we regulate AI will certainly shape the pathway of AI itself.
Well, I mean, to use that example, I'm certainly where there are people who don't like, for instance, how tech companies make money. They don't like the advertising and the targeted ads. And they feel like there's privacy issues. I don't really have a problem with that. I certainly know some people do. I think they call it surveillance capitalism. I don't have a problem with it.
But isn't it true that that revenue is what is sort of financing all the R&D, these companies are now doing into AI and creating the kinds of models that might actually not just create like better advertising, but create a, you know, a cornucopia of scientific advancements. That's an unexpected consequence. And before we, I think, begin thinking hard about it with this emerging technology that none of us really heard of up until 18 months ago.
Before we start thinking about ways to shape this technology, we probably should have a little humility that we don't know all the things it can be. We don't know the paths it will take. And there might be some unexpected consequences in a rush to begin shaping and guiding this technology. And even people who are really upset about digital platforms, I don't think they're saying like the internet was a bad idea and we should be an analyst. But is your view, we should not regulate AI at all?
I would be very, I would think very hard about very specific use cases. I would think very hard about existing sorts of laws on the books, things you cannot do. I think my default position would be rather than try to glamour our sort of social media concerns, which I think a lot of policymakers, because they feel like they missed the boat and social media regulation.
So now they're taking those concerns and applying into AI is to think a lot about the internet in the 1990s, in which we saw that it was an evolving technology and we decided to let it evolve and see what happened. That seems to be an example we've forgotten because we've been so overwhelmed by social media and sort of content and privacy issues. So that would be my instinct.
You just mentioned that a lot of people want to rerun the social media experiment, but with AI, this time getting ahead of it as opposed to behind it, I think that's right. Something that I often say is that I think it's very much the wrong metaphor. I think it has more like the internet or more like a foundational technology than it is like social media.
But on the other hand, one of my VCs on all of this is it in key places we got the regulation wrong, which then over time also leads to over regulation as people correct aggressively and often too late. And this to me feels completely core to the broader story you're telling, but not something you're comfortable applying here, which is the sort of growth era of the sort of early 20th century created genuine harms.
You have Richard Nixon talking about them, Ronald Reagan as president brags about signing the California Environmental Quality Act into law. And so then you have like very aggressive regulation. A disagreement I have with the people who call themselves AI accelerationists, the people are just like a letter rip is I think they're the real decelerationists.
But I think if you let the market and reasons of the world and so on in charge of AI, that is a perfect recipe to get very aggressive, very early regulation, because one terrible things are going to happen, but two people are not going to trust them. Whereas in fact, that Altman and Hassabi and Dario Amide and a bunch of the others seem very cautious and seem very concerned about what could go wrong is almost paradoxically leading to less regulation.
And I somewhat know this from reporting on these meetings or having with members of Congress, because the members of Congress trust that they're going to be careful and that they're sort of harm aware. Now, whether or not that proves to be true, I don't know. But I do think that there's a much more complicated relationship between wise regulation and the social tolerance for innovation and innovative risk than people sometimes give credit for.
I just am not sure where your confidence comes from that we will come anywhere close at this early stage to getting it right. I mean, it did not take long after the passage of the National Environmental Policy Act for the problems to become obvious. And did we correct those problems? We did not. So I guess I have low confidence at this early stage, we will get the regulation right. Nor do I have confidence that if we figure out we've gotten the regulation wrong, that those fixes will be made.
Because I think, as you know, once something has passed, it's very difficult to undo it, which is why even though it's been extremely obvious for a long time that we have a regulation, a problem, so we're making it hard to build in this country, it has been very difficult to undo those rules. But I guess then what I think, I guess I want to where your confidence comes from. Why don't have any confidence? If you know what I mean, that's why I have a job.
But I think one of the questions I have here is that I think I don't, if you don't understand my confidence, which I don't have, I don't understand your political economy. Because you agree, you believe that society is risk and tolerant.
You agree you believe that its reaction to things going wrong is going to be, to not just regulate, but to try to have a safety first approach to regulation that could be very, very dangerous for innovation, the fear people had of nuclear going wrong and a couple of major events like Chernobyl and through my island led to a level of nuclear regulation that effectively choked off the entire industry.
What seems to be to emerge from that is you need some way of balancing the fears people both have and the fears that emerge without going way too far in the other direction. But you're not going to get there, right? I mean, this seems to be the point of the history you are telling. You're not going to get there telling people, Eddish, don't be afraid, don't worry about it. And so I think what I'm interested in here is how do you think that you strike this balance?
Well, no. And I think inherently people are super risk averse. So why should we be confident? I think confidence comes from my core thesis, which is rapid growth. When the economy is growing, people become more confident. They become less risk averse.
And I don't think it's any coincidence that not only did we see light regulation of the internet in the 1990s, but other times where we've had fast economic growth, we've been able to take more risks with social policy such as a civil rights act like good things happen when an economy is growing quickly. So I think that would be very helpful if we went through a period of rapid growth for us to have more confidence that like, you know what? Technology is going well. The economy is going well.
Let's go easy on AI. But doesn't wealth and growth lead, I mean, in the model we've been talking about, to more regulation, to less risk tolerance? I mean, it wasn't the 70s coming on the tail end of a long period of wealth and growth. Right. At a certain point, right, people become more willing to have less growth. But I would hope that after the past half century of going through a period where were that kind of risk aversion has turned out to be the riskiest possible thing.
I mean, we're in sort of this populist moment. And one reason I think that you get populist moments because people think the government is really incompetent, particularly on economics. We've had this period where we've had a war people didn't think very well. We had a global financial crisis, bit of pandemic that people, you know, maybe we responded well as we mentioned earlier, but we didn't seem to be particularly well prepared for so yes, I'm talking about learning from history.
I think that's a good place to end. All of us are final question. What are three books you'd recommend to the audience? One book which greatly influenced my book was the book Why Information Grows, which is by a physicist named Cesar Hildago, who presents it's a very different way of thinking about economic growth rather than merely thinking about labor and capital and land, all sort of the foundational aspect you may have learned in a high school economics class.
He thinks what matters is connection, people connecting with each other, companies and people and universities and even countries. So that sort of connection economics and economic openness is really sort of at the heart of the vision I tried to give in my book.
I would also recommend, since I write about a sci-fi so much on my book, The Expans Series, which they turned into a TV series, which I view, I may be in the minority, that I view as a future, optimist, hard science series, because it shows Earth a few hundred years from now that has sort of mastered the solar system, but it's not a perfect world. Things have gone wrong. Like climate change was bad, though we seem to have gotten a hold of that.
And technology has meant there are people out of work and on basic income. So it's not a perfect world, but nothing in my vision is about creating utopia. It's about solving problems and maybe that's solution will create another problem, but we keep moving forward. And that's what I think The Expans Series does.
My final book is the American Dream is Not Dead by one of my AI colleagues, Michael Strain, which is sort of a no-nonsense look at issues like wage stagnation, income inequality, and the supposed gap between productivity, there's productivity again, and worker pay. And I think it's a bit of a myth, but very cautious myth-busting book that what you may think about all those issues may not be true, so it's a pretty great book. Jim Bethicukus, thank you very much. Thanks for having me.
This episode at The Osoclan Show is produced by Roland Hu. In fact, checking by Michelle Harris with Mary Marge Locker and Kate Sinclair, our senior engineer is Jeff Geld with additional mixing by Almanz Sahota and Isaac Jones. Our senior editor is Claire Gordon. The show's production team includes Andy Galvin, Elias Isquip, and Kristen Lin. We've original music by Isaac Jones, Audien Stratje by Christina Simuluski and Shannon Busta.
The executive producer of New York Times and Pinin Audio is Andy Roastrosser and special thanks to Sonya Herald.